共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
2.
3.
4.
Nicola Phillips 《Third world quarterly》2013,34(4):565-583
The splintering of the Mercosur following the Brazilian devaluation in early 1999 has given way to an important re-crafting of the regional vision and a significant expansion of the scope of the regional project. This article contends that these trends can best be understood as coalescing into a new (and nascent) form of regionalist governance in the Southern Cone, in which the Mercosur is reconfigured as a vehicle for a new set of developmentalist and strategic objectives. This emerging form of regionalist governance is both causative and indicative of a new political economy both of the subregion and of the wider region of the Americas, and reflective of the crystallisation of a new political economy of development. 相似文献
5.
John Nauright 《Third world quarterly》2013,34(7):1325-1336
During the past three decades sport has assumed an ever greater role within the globalisation process and in the regeneration of national, regional and local identities in the postcolonial and global age. With much of global culture displayed by the media, events, particularly significant sporting ones such as the Olympic Games or the soccer World Cup, have become highly sought after commodities as developed countries, and increasingly some leading developing countries, move towards event-driven economies. In the process, however, many countries are left behind without the necessary infrastructure or visibility to compete successfully. Furthermore, the process of displaying a culture in the lead-up to an event and during the event itself has had to focus on ready-made markets, thus reinforcing stereotypes about a place and its people. This paper discusses the paradoxes and inequalities brought on by the sport-media-tourism complex that drives the emphasis on global sporting events. 相似文献
6.
7.
8.
Understanding Belarus: economy and political landscape 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Grigory Ioffe 《欧亚研究》2004,56(1):85-118
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
Stephen G. Bunker Paul S. Ciccantell 《Studies in Comparative International Development (SCID)》2003,37(4):3-30
The causes and consequences of inequality between national economies, the ascent to dominance within the world hierarchy of
economies, and the dynamics driving the material intensification and spatial expansion of production and trade in the world
economy have long been core questions in a wide range of fields concerned with economic change and development and with international
relations. In this article, we propose that one of the fundamental mechanisms driving all three of these processes for at
least the last 500 years has been a dynamic tension, or contradiction, between the economies of scale that reduce relative
costs and drive national economic ascent to dominance in world production and trade, and the diseconomies of space that result
from the increased consumption of raw materials that this expanded production entails. The four most rapid cases of economic
ascent in the history of the world economy—Holland, Great Britain, the United States, and Japan—resolved this contradiction
in similar ways that drove the ascent of these economies to the top of the system of global stratification.
Stephen G. Bunker is professor of sociology at the University of Wisconsin-Madison. His research examines how the world economy
is driven by raw materials and transport, including the role of the Brazilian Amazon as a raw-materials periphery and the
political economy and ecology of Japanese raw-materials access strategies.
Paul S. Ciccantell is associate professor of sociology at Western Michigan University. His research examines the socioeconomic
and environmental impact of raw-materials extraction in Brazil, Canada, Mexico, and Venezuela; the organizational sociology
of raw-materials and transport industries; the impacts of the North American Free Trade Agreement; and the political economy
and ecology of Japanese raw-materials access strategies. 相似文献
16.
17.
T. J. Byres 《发展研究杂志》2013,49(2):189-207
Peruvian statistics were examined to see if construction remained labour‐intensive during 1955–67. Data on output, employment, capital, and materials consumption were either lacking or had defects that made a direct comparison of trends impossible. But conclusions could be drawn from relative price and wage trends. If materials and capital had not been substituted for labour, average construction costs would have risen substantially more than they did. Our estimate was that by 1967 they would have been 25 per cent higher. Evidence from a sample of firms, however, suggested that adoption of labour‐saving techniques cannot be tied simply to changes in wages compared with other costs. All eleven innovations studied, it is true, were markedly labour‐saving; but the rate of adoption did not closely follow wage changes. Adoption came most often during those less tense years when builders were neither overstrained with orders nor lacking credit and clients. One must conclude that both rising wages and innovations can limit employment expansion in relatively poor countries. Since both agriculture and manufacturing have been unable to absorb the growing labour force of poor countries, economists have turned their attention to other sectors for supplementary employment expansion. One of these is construction. The construction sector creates not only jobs but builds capital goods with a desirable low import content. In association with carefully structured financial institutions, it may even generate savings. How much employment a given expansion of construction will provide depends on the production functions of the sector: their slopes and their potential shifts. One must find the changes in labour productivity that go with likely changes in volume, capital accumulation, trends in material supplies, and alternate technologies. All these questions will get imprecise answers without good statistics on output, labour, capital, and materials, both unit prices and volume. If output varies in composition and in the relative quality of components, problems of weighting and aggregating arise. Because of the sector's ? instability and footloose nature, data on construction remain inferior compared with other sectors even in the most advanced and statistics‐rich countries. Can one make anything of the sorts of data available in poor countries where the sector must play its most crucial role? In this article, using rather limited data, we note with considerable alarm that steady labour intensity and corresponding employment expansion cannot be taken for granted. Where daily wages are but a fraction of hourly American wages, and where interest rates are a multiple of American rates, the more lavish use of materials and machinery compared with labour can nevertheless begin early. Peru is the country selected for our study. During 1955–67 Peru had a relatively high national output growth rate of 5.6 per cent together with a moderate rate of inflation of about 9 per cent. Except for the devaluation years of 1958 and 1967, flourishing exports of fishmeal, copper, cotton, and sugar helped carry this rate of growth. Lima was one of the continent's fastest‐growing cities in population and building, particularly in squatter barriadas. But in the 1960s commercial conduction also grew at more than a 15 per cent compound rate, measured in square metres built, according to some estimates.1 During 1964–68, construction had high priority under President Fernando Belaunde, a professional architect. More U.S. foreign aid for housing (direct and guaranteed private loans) went to Peru in absolute terms during this period than to any other country. We shall analyse the consequences by examining (1) trends in relative costs, (2) relative output and import trends, and (3) data about receptivity to innovations in a sample of firms. 相似文献
18.
19.