首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1895篇
  免费   87篇
各国政治   154篇
工人农民   93篇
世界政治   152篇
外交国际关系   139篇
法律   950篇
中国共产党   2篇
中国政治   24篇
政治理论   462篇
综合类   6篇
  2023年   15篇
  2022年   19篇
  2021年   44篇
  2020年   58篇
  2019年   70篇
  2018年   75篇
  2017年   81篇
  2016年   84篇
  2015年   66篇
  2014年   79篇
  2013年   322篇
  2012年   73篇
  2011年   66篇
  2010年   50篇
  2009年   53篇
  2008年   58篇
  2007年   71篇
  2006年   64篇
  2005年   48篇
  2004年   53篇
  2003年   53篇
  2002年   58篇
  2001年   28篇
  2000年   31篇
  1999年   23篇
  1998年   29篇
  1997年   28篇
  1996年   24篇
  1995年   17篇
  1994年   20篇
  1993年   25篇
  1992年   21篇
  1991年   16篇
  1990年   15篇
  1989年   16篇
  1988年   24篇
  1987年   7篇
  1986年   5篇
  1985年   5篇
  1984年   14篇
  1983年   4篇
  1982年   8篇
  1981年   7篇
  1979年   9篇
  1978年   8篇
  1977年   6篇
  1973年   3篇
  1972年   3篇
  1971年   3篇
  1969年   4篇
排序方式: 共有1982条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
101.
Subscribing to a Burkean view of representation, legislators have long tended to resist constant public scrutiny. In recent years, however, they have overcome this reluctance in a large number of countries and voted to allow the televising of their proceedings. But why they did so remains a mystery. Some media theorists argue that television exposure is a 'great democratizer'. It demystifies public authority figures and obliges them to become more accountable for their actions. The experience of the British House of Lords and the United States Senate suggests instead that television was invited in by rational political actors as a means of achieving their goals in a time of change. In this view, television is best seen not as a force in its own right, but as a medium of communication that can be strategically deployed by goal-oriented political élites responding to different political circumstances and institutional incentive structures.  相似文献   
102.
I gratefully acknowledge the comments of Jan Potters and Joep Sonnemans on an earlier version of this paper.  相似文献   
103.
Using a behavioral model of political decisionmaking, it is argued that an increasing population size and/or an increasing efficiency of production in a private enterprise economy relative to a centrally planned economy may create the conditions for a self-interested nomenklatura in a Soviet-type economy to consider a transition to a market economy. This transition may be thwarted, however, by the threat for prospective private enterpreneurs of exploitation after the change of regime. Some form of political pluralism guaranteeing sufficient political influence to private entrepreneurs appears to be required for a successful transition. The analysis shows that such a combined political and economic reform can be in the interest of the nomenklatura, thereby providing an endogenous behavioral explanation for a change of regime.  相似文献   
104.
105.
Indigenous and linguistic minorities are in an inferior economic and social position. The ethnic concentration of inequality is increasingly being recognized in the literature. In this review, studies from six Latin American countries that estimate the costs to an individual of being an economic minority are reviewed. The studies decompose the overall earnings gap into two components. One is the portion attributable to differences in the endowments of income-generating characteristics (“explained” differences) and the other is attributable to differences in the returns that majority and minority workers receive for the same endowment of income-generating characteristics (“unexplained”). This latter component is often taken as reflecting the “upper bound” of wage discrimination. In two studies for Bolivia, one using a 1966 survey and the other a 1989 survey, decomposition of the differential between indigenous and nonindigenous earnings leads to the conclusion that most of the overall differential is due to productivity. In Guatemala, Mexico and Peru, only one-half of the earnings differential can be attributed to differences in productivity-enhancing characteristics. In Paraguay, decomposition of the overall earnings differential between monolingual Spanish speakers and Guaraní speakers shows that most of the differential is explained by human capital differences. In Brazil, however, there is a significant cost to “being non-white.” Harry Anthony Patrinos is a Senior Education Economist at the World Bank. He leads the Economics of Education Thematic Group and manages EdInvest (www.worldbank.org/edinvest), the Education Investment Information Facility. He is co-author ofDecentralization of Education: Demand-Side Financing (1997). His latest co-edited book isPolicy Analysis of Child Labor: A Comparative Study (St. Martin's Press, 1999).Indigenous People and Poverty in Latin America: An Empirical Analysis (edited with George Psacharopoulos), was one of the first studies of the socioeconomic situation of indigenous peoples in Latin America.  相似文献   
106.

Volume Contents

Contents of Volume 19 (2000)  相似文献   
107.
The public choice literature contains little formal analysis of the bureaucratic choice of production modes — public or private — of publicly funded services. An important question to be addressed is why some governmental bodies choose to provide a publicly funded service with publicly owned and operated production units whereas other governmental bodies contract with private firms to provide the same publicly funded service. This paper is the first formal attempt to remedy this gap in the literature. We develop a theoretical explanation of the government decision maker's choice between public and private production modes based on utility maximizing behavior. We then examine empirically this choice employing logit analysis. The empirical results, which include several tests for robustness, confirm our theoretical explanation. The results are significant and suggest that non-monetary constraints are an important factor affecting this choice of production modes and that monetary constraints are less influential.  相似文献   
108.
109.
110.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号