首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   172篇
  免费   4篇
各国政治   19篇
工人农民   7篇
世界政治   22篇
外交国际关系   2篇
法律   78篇
中国政治   2篇
政治理论   46篇
  2022年   2篇
  2017年   2篇
  2014年   4篇
  2013年   11篇
  2012年   7篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   9篇
  2009年   6篇
  2008年   11篇
  2007年   9篇
  2006年   10篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   4篇
  2001年   2篇
  1999年   2篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   5篇
  1995年   3篇
  1994年   5篇
  1992年   3篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   3篇
  1986年   3篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   2篇
  1982年   2篇
  1980年   4篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   3篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   1篇
  1970年   1篇
  1969年   1篇
  1968年   1篇
  1964年   2篇
  1961年   1篇
  1960年   1篇
  1959年   1篇
  1958年   1篇
  1953年   1篇
  1944年   2篇
排序方式: 共有176条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
111.
112.
PARENTAL SUPERVISION RE-EXAMINED   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
  相似文献   
113.
SCOTT WILSON 《当代中国》2008,17(54):25-51
Since 1978, China has opened itself to foreign direct investment and has undertaken significant legal reform, especially in the area of international commercial arbitration. I analyze the roles that foreign actors and state officials have played in changing Chinese legal institutions such as the Chinese International Economic and Trade Arbitration Commission (CIETAC) and personal relations, or guanxi. 1 1. La guanxi is a Chinese expression, meaning ‘to pull strings (to get things done)’. View all notes Foreign investors, attorneys, and non-governmental organizations are helping China to adopt formal commercial arbitral institutions that follow international norms. In that sense, foreign actors are contributing to rule of law in China. Yet, foreign investors also attempt to use guanxi to get around central regulations, thereby contributing to informal legal institutions. The combination of guanxi and formal legal institutions follows a model of path dependent institutional change. I use the terms, ‘layering’ and ‘bricolage’ to elucidate the ways that actors combine existing institutions with new legal forms introduced by foreign investors, attorneys, and NGOs.  相似文献   
114.
Since a gender‐free society has never existed historically, feminist thinking that posits the equality of the sexes is inherently Utopian. Feminist Utopian writers, working within the traditional genre of science‐fiction, a genre particularly well‐suited to revolutionary theoretical discussions, have explored three types of feminist utopias: all‐female societies, biological androgyny, and genuinely egalitarian two‐sex societies. This essay examines examples of feminist utopias in each of these three paradigms to determine to what extent they are “abstract” (in Ernst Bloch's terminology), ie. merely wish‐fulfillment fantasies, and to what extent “concrete” and thus viable blue‐prints for future political and social organization.  相似文献   
115.
116.
Professional influence in policy‐making is generally believed to rest on professionals successfully laying claim to access to expertise – knowledge, understanding or experience – not available to others, above all politicians. On the basis of a 2005 survey of nearly 800 lawyers serving in local authorities in England and Wales, this article explores the relationship between specialization and political influence. Lawyers who shape policy use conventional routes for political influence, establish contacts with political officeholders, tend to identify less with the profession at large and are less likely to see themselves as specialists in any field of law. This means that the relationship between expertise and political power is complex and that the notion that professionals use their expertise to shape policy should be treated with some caution.  相似文献   
117.
118.
BRIAN BIX 《Ratio juris》2007,20(1):45-55
Abstract. The article considers Robert Summers' new book ( Summers 2006 ), in the context of Summers' earlier work and the role of form and formalism in other jurisprudential discussions. While accepting the value of a form‐centered approach to studying law, the article questions Summers' claim that his approach is clearly superior to (and not merely complementary with) traditional analytic theories, like those of Hart and Kelsen. The article also suggests that the book's discussion of form in contract and commercial law is somewhat disappointing, given Summers' expertise in this area, and the many difficult form‐related questions that area raises.  相似文献   
119.
120.
A substantial literature exists on the economic analysis of bureaucracy, which includes formal models of bureaucratic behaviour by Niskanen (1971) and Dunleavy (1991). This article develops hypotheses from those models about changes in size of bureaux over time and tests them against data on the Australian federal budget sector in 1982–83 and 1991–92. The models predict that bureaucrats usually will be able to influence the size or structure of their bureaux in line with their personal preferences. However, the Australian data suggest that the extent of such influence may be less than is assumed in either model and that the preferences of politicians are more influential than the models allow. One conclusion is that, if bureaucracy is to be modelled, a principal-agent approach will have more to offer than the neo-classical maximizing framework adopted by Niskanen in particular. A further conclusion, at odds with those of Niskanen and weakening his case for wholesale privatization, is that bureaucratic dysfunctions may be amenable to reform of the political and bureaucratic rules and systems.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号