首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   969篇
  免费   29篇
各国政治   74篇
工人农民   30篇
世界政治   86篇
外交国际关系   61篇
法律   424篇
中国政治   13篇
政治理论   304篇
综合类   6篇
  2023年   5篇
  2022年   3篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   10篇
  2019年   27篇
  2018年   30篇
  2017年   29篇
  2016年   35篇
  2015年   20篇
  2014年   23篇
  2013年   183篇
  2012年   24篇
  2011年   26篇
  2010年   26篇
  2009年   29篇
  2008年   34篇
  2007年   23篇
  2006年   33篇
  2005年   31篇
  2004年   36篇
  2003年   32篇
  2002年   24篇
  2001年   25篇
  2000年   19篇
  1999年   18篇
  1998年   17篇
  1997年   16篇
  1996年   13篇
  1995年   15篇
  1994年   14篇
  1993年   18篇
  1992年   11篇
  1991年   12篇
  1990年   10篇
  1989年   14篇
  1988年   12篇
  1987年   12篇
  1986年   10篇
  1985年   9篇
  1984年   12篇
  1983年   6篇
  1982年   5篇
  1981年   6篇
  1980年   4篇
  1979年   4篇
  1978年   5篇
  1975年   3篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   3篇
  1969年   4篇
排序方式: 共有998条查询结果,搜索用时 62 毫秒
901.
Jones  Philip  Hudson  John 《Public Choice》1998,94(1-2):175-189
This paper explores the proposition that political parties reduce the ‘transaction costs’ of electoral participation. Political parties provide a low cost signal of a candidate's policies and personal characteristics and, in this way, reduce voters' information costs. With reference to ‘transaction cost economics’, political parties offer an ‘implicit contract’ between voters and politicians and thereby reduce the scope for opportunism by politicians. This impact on transaction costs is important in any evaluation of public policy towards political parties.  相似文献   
902.
903.
904.
905.
906.
907.
908.
Goodman  John C.  Porter  Philip K. 《Public Choice》2004,120(3-4):247-266

This paper treats interest groups – peoplein their role as consumers of a public goodand people in their role as taxpayers – asthe unit of account for representativevoting. Each group is allowed to make aneffort to support its preferred candidateand, at the margin, the effort-benefitratio is the political price the group iswilling to pay to secure an additionaldollar of benefits.

Under reasonable assumptions, a uniqueequilibrium is assured and itscharacteristics are quite intuitive. Inparticular, the marginal political benefit(from consumers) of the last unit of outputmust equal the marginal political cost(from taxpayers). Alternatively, the rateat which the politician can transformtaxpayer income into consumer surplus mustequal the ratio of their political prices. The result will be optimal only on the rareoccasion when the effort-benefit ratios ofthe two groups are equal.

Since political goals are themselves ``public goods'' for thetwo interest groups,they face all the normal free riderproblems. Moreover, even small differencesin the effort-benefit ratios of the twogroups lead to large welfare losses.

How bad can things get? Each group has anincentive to try to overcome free-riderproblems and divert resources from privatesector activities to politics. And anyincrease in political effort is alwaysrewarded. However, (1) the marginal returnis always higher for the group with thesmaller effort-benefit ratio; (2) thedifferential return between the two groupsgrows the further we stray from optimality;and (3) both groups face diminishingreturns. These incentives may act asnatural checks on political outcomes –placing some limit on the amount of wasteand inefficiency democracy is likely toproduce.

The influence of a producer (of the publicgood) group that collects a rent increasesthe likelihood that public goods will beoverproduced. In fact, it is conceivableto have a good with no value to consumersproduced, solely because of the influenceof producers. Comparative static analysisreveal that the political system willrespond to changes in market conditions ina way similar to economic markets. Themagnitude of these shifts differs fromeconomic markets, however. For goods thatare being overproduced, the politicalmarketplace overresponds to changes indemand and underresponds to changes incosts. The converse is true for goods thatare being underproduced.

  相似文献   
909.
One of the thorniest issues of intergovernmental fiscal relations is state oversight of local fiscal affairs. States have oversight responsibility and must take action when local governments run afoul of responsible fiscal behavior. Less accepted is how states can detect local financial difficulties before they become emergencies that require state takeover. Research in the 1970s provided some assistance to states wishing to recognize local financial emergencies. But the time has come to look at this issue anew, particularly with an eye toward predicting local financial problems before they become serious. This article describes a 10-point scale that predicts these problems and tests the scale to predict local fiscal stress in a sample of Michigan local governments.  相似文献   
910.
Government‐funded training programs in the United States have often been subject to rigorous evaluation. Indeed, many of these programs have been evaluated with random assignment, although sophisticated quasi‐experimental methods have also been used. Until very recently, however, there has been little systematic attempt to use the cumulative information vested in these evaluations to attempt determine which kinds of programs work best in which setting and with respect to which types of client. Meta‐analysis—a set of statistical procedures for systematically synthesizing findings from separate studies—can, in theory at least, address these and other topics that evaluation of individual programs cannot. This article discusses the steps in conducting such a synthesis, summarizes the results of three recently conducted meta‐analyses of training and welfare‐to‐work programs, identifies limitations to the meta‐analytic approach, and considers ways in which some of these limitations can be overcome.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号