首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1287篇
  免费   71篇
各国政治   115篇
工人农民   54篇
世界政治   92篇
外交国际关系   66篇
法律   668篇
中国政治   5篇
政治理论   349篇
综合类   9篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   12篇
  2022年   14篇
  2021年   15篇
  2020年   33篇
  2019年   44篇
  2018年   68篇
  2017年   83篇
  2016年   63篇
  2015年   53篇
  2014年   74篇
  2013年   181篇
  2012年   56篇
  2011年   60篇
  2010年   57篇
  2009年   50篇
  2008年   40篇
  2007年   73篇
  2006年   39篇
  2005年   66篇
  2004年   51篇
  2003年   36篇
  2002年   24篇
  2001年   25篇
  2000年   25篇
  1999年   21篇
  1998年   10篇
  1997年   13篇
  1996年   6篇
  1995年   3篇
  1994年   7篇
  1993年   2篇
  1992年   4篇
  1991年   3篇
  1990年   5篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   2篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   8篇
  1981年   4篇
  1980年   1篇
  1979年   3篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   2篇
  1976年   2篇
  1974年   1篇
  1969年   1篇
排序方式: 共有1358条查询结果,搜索用时 46 毫秒
131.
132.
133.
134.
135.
Given the nature of knowledge and characteristics of the intellectual property rights system, technological transactions tend to be governed by contracts that are costly and not highly profitable. This explains why there are so few technology licensing agreements. However, in some situations, private and specific institutions tend to enable property rights to be more precise, knowledge transfers to be easier, and technology licensing agreements to be less complex to design and to run. This explains why there is a concentration of technology licensing agreements in some industries and in some relational situations. These shed light on the design of firms’ strategies to valorize intellectual assets and of public policies to stimulate innovation and diffusion.  相似文献   
136.
Karl Wärneryd 《Public Choice》1994,80(3-4):371-380
Intuitively, we associate different political parties with different types of policy. In contrast, this paper shows that in the absence of differential costs of membership among parties (that is, if party membership ischeap talk), party labels cannot perfectly signal the ideologies of candidates. However, under certain conditions parties can signal candidate types imperfectly. The paper therefore also provides an example of how costless communication can be effective in games of partial conflict.  相似文献   
137.
138.
Leadership is a matter of both intentions and perceptions, which do not necessarily always match. Because employees’ motivation and commitment are only affected by leadership if they notice it, employee‐perceived leadership is expected to have a stronger correlation with organizational performance than leader‐intended leadership. This expectation is tested for transformational and transactional leadership, as both types of practices are expected to increase performance. Using a sample of 1,621 teachers and 79 Danish high school principals, the authors find that leader‐intended and employee‐perceived transformational and transactional leadership are only weakly correlated and that only employee‐perceived leadership practices (both transformational and transactional) are significantly related to objectively measured school performance. The results show that it is important to distinguish between intended and perceived leadership and that leaders should be aware of how their practices are perceived.  相似文献   
139.
Legislators claim that how they explain their votes matters as much as or more than the roll calls themselves. However, few studies have systematically examined legislators’ explanations and citizen attitudes in response to these explanations. We theorize that legislators strategically tailor explanations to constituents in order to compensate for policy choices that are incongruent with constituent preferences, and to reinforce policy choices that are congruent. We conduct a within‐subjects field experiment using U.S. senators as subjects to test this hypothesis. We then conduct a between‐subjects survey experiment of ordinary people to see how they react to the explanatory strategies used by senators in the field experiment. We find that most senators tailor their explanations to their audiences, and that these tailored explanations are effective at currying support—especially among people who disagree with the legislators’ roll‐call positions.  相似文献   
140.
We model two aspects of executives in parliamentary democracies: Decision‐making authority is assigned to individuals, and private information is aggregated through communication. When information is relevant to all policies and communication is private, all decisions should be centralized to a single politician. A government that holds cabinet meetings, where information is made available to all decision makers, outperforms one where communication is private: A multimember cabinet can be optimal; it need not be single peaked around the most moderate politician or ideologically connected. Centralization is nonmonotonic in the degree of ideological divergence. In a large cabinet, all power should be given to the most moderate politician. Even when uncertainty is policy specific and a single politician is informed on each policy, power should never be fully decentralized. Our model provides a justification for centralized authority and cabinet meetings that enhance the quality of policy.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号