首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   258篇
  免费   13篇
各国政治   27篇
工人农民   4篇
世界政治   34篇
外交国际关系   17篇
法律   129篇
中国共产党   1篇
政治理论   57篇
综合类   2篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   3篇
  2022年   5篇
  2021年   6篇
  2020年   7篇
  2019年   17篇
  2018年   25篇
  2017年   16篇
  2016年   15篇
  2015年   13篇
  2014年   12篇
  2013年   33篇
  2012年   12篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   13篇
  2009年   15篇
  2008年   10篇
  2007年   16篇
  2006年   8篇
  2005年   9篇
  2004年   7篇
  2003年   2篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   3篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   2篇
  1992年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1987年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
排序方式: 共有271条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
131.
Electoral institutions should systematically affect the propensity of a country to rely and spend on distributive measures. Supporting evidence is however still rare because of the difficulty in finding comparable cross-national data, the employment of dummy variables to account for the electoral systems, and the failure to recognise the interacting effects of different electoral rules on policy outcomes. Employing national data on state aid expenditure and a number of measures across European Union countries, the article provides evidence that legislators elected in higher magnitude districts spend less. More interestingly, it shows the interlocking policy effects of electoral institutions. Where high district magnitude is combined with ballot control, party-based voting and pooling, these rules conjunctly dampen politicians’ incentives to cultivate a personal vote and lead to lower spending on, and use of, distributive measures. Where high district magnitude is not combined with these rules, results are inconclusive. With one exception though, if leaders do not have control over the ballot rank, higher magnitude increases reliance on distributive measures. Results are robust to several alternative political-economy explanations of fiscal policy outcomes.  相似文献   
132.
We reply to the comment of John Carey and Simon Hix on our original contribution entitled “District Magnitude and Representation of the Majority’s Preferences: Quasi-Experimental Evidence from Popular and Parliamentary Votes” in Public Choice 151:585–610 (2012). District magnitude does not necessarily affect deviations between political representatives and their district voters in a strictly monotonic way but monotonicity is upheld for deviations between representatives and the national majority. We provide new perspectives and caution against evaluating electoral systems by focusing on individual politicians’ behavior but neglecting aggregation effects.  相似文献   
133.
Gallegati  Marco  Tamberi  Massimo 《Public Choice》2022,192(3-4):227-248
Public Choice - Adopting an international historical perspective, this study aims to identify the main empirical regularities in the long-run growth pattern of government expenditure. The...  相似文献   
134.
This paper offers empirical evidence about transaction cost in Russia. After relating empirical measures of information and liquidity to corporate characteristics, competitive theories about cross-listings are tested. Since cross-listings generate competitive effects on transaction costs, potential to affect price discovery exists. The results reveal a lower share of private information for cross-listed firms since more transparent accounting standards reduce the incentives to collect superior information. Robustness for the evidence presented in favor of the legal bonding hypothesis is provided by those firms which list with the highest Russian standards. Measures of information-based trade are lower and the likelihood of listing abroad is significantly higher.  相似文献   
135.
136.
Politics must address multiple problems simultaneously. In an ideal world, political competition would force parties to adopt priorities that reflect the voters' true concerns. In reality, parties can run their campaigns in such a way as to manipulate voters' priorities. This phenomenon, known as priming, may allow parties to underinvest in solving the issues that they intend to mute. We develop a model of endogenous issue ownership in which two vote‐seeking parties (a) invest in policy quality to increase the value of their platform and (b) choose a communication strategy to prime voters. We identify novel feedback between communication and investment. In particular, we find that stronger priming effects can constrain parties to invest more resources in all issues. We also identify the conditions under which parties prefer to focus on their “historical issues” or to engage in “issue stealing.”  相似文献   
137.
138.
139.
欧洲专利申请程序及途径介析   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
在欧洲申请专利有四种途径:直接适用国内程序;直接适用欧洲专利局程序;国内程序和专利合作条约程序相结合;欧洲专利局程序和专利合作条约程序相结合。不同申请途径的主要程序各不相同、各有不足。对这些程序进行介绍和分析,有助于专利代理人了解欧洲专利申请,以更好地为客户服务。  相似文献   
140.
In this article, we explore the possibility that the percentage of litigations settled outside of court is affected by the degree of contingency of lawyers’ fees. In our view, a litigation is a game where not only the plaintiff and the defendant, but also their lawyers are independent players. The main consequence of this assumption is that the authority to settle is allocated endogenously to either the clients or their lawyers, depending on the value of the relevant parameters. In this game theoretical setup, (1) we compare the incentives to settle provided by contingent and non-contingent lawyers’ fees, and (2) we state the conditions under which settlement is more likely to happen.   相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号