全文获取类型
收费全文 | 23671篇 |
免费 | 322篇 |
专业分类
各国政治 | 1102篇 |
工人农民 | 814篇 |
世界政治 | 2003篇 |
外交国际关系 | 1276篇 |
法律 | 12732篇 |
中国共产党 | 2篇 |
中国政治 | 125篇 |
政治理论 | 5695篇 |
综合类 | 244篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 153篇 |
2020年 | 315篇 |
2019年 | 414篇 |
2018年 | 472篇 |
2017年 | 565篇 |
2016年 | 607篇 |
2015年 | 429篇 |
2014年 | 506篇 |
2013年 | 2648篇 |
2012年 | 578篇 |
2011年 | 601篇 |
2010年 | 511篇 |
2009年 | 568篇 |
2008年 | 618篇 |
2007年 | 678篇 |
2006年 | 622篇 |
2005年 | 603篇 |
2004年 | 627篇 |
2003年 | 628篇 |
2002年 | 604篇 |
2001年 | 805篇 |
2000年 | 737篇 |
1999年 | 618篇 |
1998年 | 387篇 |
1997年 | 338篇 |
1996年 | 298篇 |
1995年 | 296篇 |
1994年 | 339篇 |
1993年 | 293篇 |
1992年 | 420篇 |
1991年 | 459篇 |
1990年 | 393篇 |
1989年 | 410篇 |
1988年 | 376篇 |
1987年 | 399篇 |
1986年 | 406篇 |
1985年 | 399篇 |
1984年 | 331篇 |
1983年 | 377篇 |
1982年 | 300篇 |
1981年 | 290篇 |
1980年 | 215篇 |
1979年 | 280篇 |
1978年 | 202篇 |
1977年 | 181篇 |
1976年 | 162篇 |
1975年 | 146篇 |
1974年 | 166篇 |
1973年 | 134篇 |
1972年 | 127篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
221.
When Does Deliberation Begin? Internal Reflection versus Public Discussion in Deliberative Democracy 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Political deliberation involves both internal reflection and public discussion. The former might be far more important than implied by deliberative democrats' heavy emphasis on the discursive component. Analysis of the deliberations of a citizen's jury on an Australian environmental issue shows jurors' attitudes changing more in response to the 'information' phase of the jury proceedings, involving a large degree of 'deliberation within', than during the formal 'discussion' phase. Various ways can be imagined for evoking internal reflection of that sort, even in mass-political settings. 相似文献
222.
Justice and Culture: Rawls, Sen, Nussbaum and O'Neill 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Is it possible, in a multicultural world, to hold all societies to a common standard of decency that is both high enough to protect basic human interests, and yet not biased in the direction of particular cultural values? We examine the recent work of four liberals – John Rawls, Amartya Sen, Martha Nussbaum and Onora O'Neill – to see whether any of them has given a successful answer to this question. For Rawls, the decency standard is set by reference to an idea of basic human rights that we argue offers too little protection to members of non-liberal societies. Sen and Nussbaum both employ the idea of human capabilities, but in interestingly different ways: for Sen the problems are how to weight different capabilities, and how to decide which are basic, whereas for Nussbaum the difficulty is that her favoured list of capabilities depends on an appeal to autonomy that is unlikely to be acceptable to non-liberal cultures. O'Neill rejects a rights-based approach in favour of a neo-Kantian position that asks which principles of action people everywhere could consent to, but this also may be too weak in the face of cultural diversity. We conclude that liberals need to argue both for a minimum decency standard and for the full set of liberal rights as the best guarantors of that standard over time. 相似文献
223.
Claudio J. Katz 《American journal of political science》2003,47(1):1-17
This article reassesses Thomas Jefferson's political economy in light of debates about the influence of liberal and republican ideas on his thought. I argue that Jefferson embraced liberal premises, but used them to reach anticapitalist conclusions. He opposed neither commerce nor the prosperity it promised; he opposed working for a wage, and he did so on liberal grounds. The first section of this article shows that John Locke's theory of property turns on the justification of capitalist labor relations. The second section establishes, first, that Locke's argument played a decisive role in the development of Jefferson's own and, second, that Jefferson redefined its terms to fashion a forceful critique of wage labor. An examination of Jefferson's writings elucidates a neglected variant of the liberal tradition, prevalent in the United States until the Populist agitation. Its core is the stigma attached to working for hire as a diminished form of liberty, tantamount to wage slavery. 相似文献
224.
David Stasavage 《American journal of political science》2003,47(3):389-402
Debates about the appropriate mix between autonomy and accountability of bureaucrats are relevant to numerous areas of government action. I examine whether there is evidence of a tradeoff between transparency, democratic accountability, and the gains from monetary delegation. I begin by presenting a simple theoretical model which suggests that central banks that are transparent, in the sense of publishing their macroeconomic forecasts, will find it easier to acquire a reputation. Despite making central banks more subject to outside scrutiny then, monetary transparency can lead to improved economic outcomes. I also consider arguments about the effect of accountability provisions involving parliamentary oversight and control over central bankers. The article then uses a new data set to examine these issues empirically, focusing on a natural experiment involving disinflation costs under different central banking institutions during the 1990s. Results suggest that countries with more transparent central banks face lower costs of disinflation while accountability provisions have no clear effect on disinflation costs. My results also concord with earlier findings that the effect of monetary institutions is conditional on other features of the political environment. 相似文献
225.
Thomas J. Rudolph 《American journal of political science》2003,47(4):698-713
The concept of responsibility lies at the heart of theories of democratic accountability. This article represents the first attempt to explicitly model attributions of presidential versus congressional responsibility for the economy. The article investigates the extent to which contextual and individual-level factors influence citizens' attributions of responsibility for the economy and how, in turn, such judgments shape their political evaluations. Employing a multinomial probit model of attributional choice, I find that responsibility judgments are shaped to varying degrees by economic ideology, perceptions of institutional context, and partisanship, although the effects of partisanship are not uniform across political parties. The results demonstrate that responsibility attributions are politically consequential and moderate the effects of economic perceptions on presidential and congressional approval. Finally, the results suggest that the effects of responsibility attributions in the sanctioning process are not invariant across the target of institutional evaluation . 相似文献
226.
227.
J. STANLEY MARSHALL 《政策研究评论》2003,20(4):629-634
Science education in our schools is fundamentally the same today as it was fifty years ago and the scientific method has not really changed. Good science teaching is defined as the never‐ending search for evidence, for objective data, which leads to truth, and the search for truth should be at the heart of education in all subjects at all levels, and teacher training should address this objective view point. Science in our schools is watered down with derivatives such as environmental education. Steps should be taken to increase the level of science content knowledge in schools and science teacher education. Additionally, the rules of the open market should be invoked to give science teachers the latitude to offer their services as other providers of professional services do, and receive compensation greater than they would as regular full‐time teachers. These issues are discussed with implications for policy. 相似文献
228.
Sizable economic consequences may resultfrom listing under the Endangered SpeciesAct (ESA). Potentially adversely affectedparties will attempt to use the politicalprocess to protect their interests. Thequestion is, “are listing determinationssubject to political manipulation?” Inthis paper, we explore empirically thepossibility that implementation of the ESAis determined, in part, by politicalconsiderations. Specifically, weinvestigate whether states with strongcongressional representation are able touse their political muscle to reduce thenumber of listings in their states, ascompared to states with weak congressionalrepresentation. Controlling for otherfactors, we find that states with greaterrepresentation on the U.S. Fish andWildlife Service’s budgetary oversightsubcommittee in the U.S. House ofRepresentatives have significantly fewerESA listings than states with weakerrepresentation on that subcommittee. 相似文献
229.
Politicians, Privacy and Media Intrusion in Britain 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
230.