首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   444篇
  免费   13篇
各国政治   22篇
工人农民   32篇
世界政治   55篇
外交国际关系   33篇
法律   215篇
中国政治   5篇
政治理论   91篇
综合类   4篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   7篇
  2019年   10篇
  2018年   9篇
  2017年   11篇
  2016年   11篇
  2015年   7篇
  2014年   6篇
  2013年   64篇
  2012年   7篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   7篇
  2009年   13篇
  2008年   12篇
  2007年   11篇
  2006年   13篇
  2005年   11篇
  2004年   13篇
  2003年   14篇
  2002年   15篇
  2001年   13篇
  2000年   12篇
  1999年   10篇
  1998年   6篇
  1997年   7篇
  1996年   7篇
  1995年   7篇
  1994年   5篇
  1993年   7篇
  1992年   5篇
  1991年   8篇
  1990年   6篇
  1989年   5篇
  1988年   9篇
  1987年   6篇
  1985年   4篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   8篇
  1982年   9篇
  1981年   4篇
  1980年   5篇
  1979年   8篇
  1978年   7篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   5篇
  1975年   6篇
  1974年   8篇
  1969年   2篇
  1967年   3篇
  1966年   2篇
排序方式: 共有457条查询结果,搜索用时 93 毫秒
111.
Mediation caucusing — that is, separate meetings conducted by the mediator with some, but not all, of the parties — is widely used, but it has become increasingly controversial, as some mediators advocate for a no‐caucus form of mediation using only joint sessions with all parties present. The rationale for the no‐caucus model is that caucuses give the mediator too much power at the expense of the parties, and joint sessions improve the parties' understanding of each other's views. But caucusing adds value to mediation in several ways. First, from the standpoint of economic theory, caucusing provides mediators with an important tool for overcoming two impediments to settlement — the “prisoner's dilemma” (caused by the parties' fear of mutual exploitation) and “adverse selection” (caused by the failure to disclose information). Second, caucusing can help the mediator overcome a variety of negotiation problems, such as communication barriers, unrealistic expectations, emotional barriers, intraparty conflict, and fear of losing face. Third, caucusing provides a more private setting in which the mediator can develop a deeper and more personal understanding of the parties' needs and interests. Although the no‐caucus model may be appropriate for certain types of mediation (particularly those cases in which the parties will have an ongoing relationship), some parties may prefer the efficiency that can be achieved with caucusing, even if that means sacrificing certain other values — such as greater understanding — or giving the mediator more information than the parties have, thus creating the risk of manipulation by the mediator. Moreover, the choice is not binary — numerous variations and hybrid formats can be useful, such as sessions in which the mediator meets with only the parties' lawyers or with only the parties. Choosing the best format for a mediation is more of an art than a science, and mediators should consider, with the parties, whether the parties' objectives would be best served using only joint sessions, extensive caucusing, or a combination of these approaches.  相似文献   
112.
This article highlights two contrasting images of tort. The first reflects the traditional portrayal of justice, depicting tort as an independent ‘natural’ system of rules of universal application forming the foundation of a just society. The second is more recent and relates to the perceived development of a damaging compensation culture. Focusing on personal injury litigation, we show how these portrayals differ from the reality of tort. In practice it is heavily influenced by institutional arrangements: the importance of both welfare provision and liability insurance is highlighted, and the effects of a ‘no‐win no‐fee’ claims market are examined. The operation of tort is very much affected by commercial interests and the economic demands of the institutions which surround it. Overall we conclude that the images of tort fail to reflect how the personal injury compensation system actually operates.  相似文献   
113.
114.
115.
116.
117.
118.
119.
An FBI investigation of county purchasing activities in the mid 1980s resulted in the conviction of 55 of Mississippi's 410 county supervisors. Analyzing data from the state's 1987 county supervisor elections and hypothesizing that candidates' demands for votes increase as the gains from holding public office increase, we predict larger voter turnouts in the 26 of the state's 82 counties where supervisor corruption was exposed. Holding constant average voter turnout in the preceding U.S. presidential election and controlling for the competitiveness of supervisor races, we find that more Mississippians indeed voted in corrupt than in non-corrupt counties.  相似文献   
120.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号