首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   11459篇
  免费   91篇
各国政治   526篇
工人农民   1133篇
世界政治   531篇
外交国际关系   529篇
法律   5809篇
中国共产党   1篇
中国政治   23篇
政治理论   2959篇
综合类   39篇
  2023年   10篇
  2022年   14篇
  2021年   34篇
  2020年   62篇
  2019年   59篇
  2018年   1347篇
  2017年   1292篇
  2016年   1113篇
  2015年   134篇
  2014年   106篇
  2013年   613篇
  2012年   267篇
  2011年   999篇
  2010年   1074篇
  2009年   686篇
  2008年   860篇
  2007年   804篇
  2006年   104篇
  2005年   168篇
  2004年   267篇
  2003年   222篇
  2002年   120篇
  2001年   72篇
  2000年   69篇
  1999年   68篇
  1998年   71篇
  1997年   66篇
  1996年   65篇
  1995年   84篇
  1994年   68篇
  1993年   46篇
  1992年   29篇
  1991年   49篇
  1990年   26篇
  1989年   41篇
  1988年   32篇
  1987年   36篇
  1986年   51篇
  1985年   15篇
  1984年   34篇
  1983年   39篇
  1982年   36篇
  1981年   19篇
  1980年   27篇
  1979年   22篇
  1978年   29篇
  1977年   25篇
  1976年   16篇
  1974年   20篇
  1973年   8篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
971.
We distinguish between (i) voting systems in which voters can rank candidates and (ii) those in which they can grade candidates, using two or more grades. In approval voting, voters can assign two grades only—approve (1) or not approve (0)—to candidates. While two grades rule out a discrepancy between the average-grade winners, who receive the highest average grade, and the superior-grade winners, who receive more superior grades in pairwise comparisons (akin to Condorcet winners), more than two grades allow it. We call this discrepancy between the two kinds of winners the paradox of grading systems, which we illustrate with several examples and whose probability we estimate for sincere and strategic voters through a Monte Carlo simulation. We discuss the tradeoff between (i) allowing more than two grades, but risking the paradox, and (ii) precluding the paradox, but restricting voters to two grades.  相似文献   
972.
973.
974.
975.
This article analyzes governmental responses for the climate change challenge in China and Brazil. Both countries have a central role in the climate change debate since they are major greenhouse gases emitters, thus contributing to the aggravation of the problem, each with differentiated participation. At the same time, policy measures aimed at climate issues in these countries may lead to the reconfiguration of international negotiations on the topic. The methodological aspects include three main points of analysis: the trajectory of greenhouse gas emissions in both countries; political and institutional structures mobilized to the climate issue and focusing on mitigation and policy responses related to climate change.  相似文献   
976.
977.
This study investigates the determinants of the ratification of International Covenant on Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights (ICESCR). To do so, it proposes an explanation that postulates that states employ treaty ratification as a device to signal their resolve to implement polices required by the treaty at issue in order to appease demanding domestic constituencies, predicting that states with lower compliance capacity tend to commit faster than states with higher compliance capacity. Applying this explanation to the ICESCR leads to two expectations. First, the larger government spending a proxy of high compliance capacity is hypothesized to delay the ratification process. Second, states with the unitary system are expected to ratify the ICESCR more promptly because the centralized power structure in unitary states significantly restricts the pursuit of the policy autonomy by minorities at local level that the right to self-determination entails. The Cox proportional hazard analysis lends support to both hypotheses.  相似文献   
978.
979.
980.
Engagement in school is crucial for academic success and school completion. Surprisingly little research has focused on the relationship between student engagement and delinquency. This study examines whether engagement predicts subsequent school and general misconduct among 4,890 inner-city Chicago elementary school students (mean age: 11 years and 4 months; 43.3% boys; 66.5% black; 28.8% Latino). To improve upon prior research in this area, we distinguish three types of engagement (emotional, behavioral, and cognitive), examine whether the relationship between engagement and misconduct is bidirectional (misconduct also impairs engagement), and control for possible common causes of low engagement and misconduct, including peer and family relationships and relatively stable indicators of risk-proneness. Emotional and behavioral engagement predict decreases in school and general delinquency. However, cognitive engagement is associated with increases in these outcomes. School and general delinquency predict decreased engagement only in the cognitive domain. Suggestions for future research and implications for policy are discussed.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号