首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   5366篇
  免费   287篇
  国内免费   1篇
各国政治   362篇
工人农民   28篇
世界政治   645篇
外交国际关系   833篇
法律   1806篇
中国共产党   483篇
中国政治   747篇
政治理论   262篇
综合类   488篇
  2023年   35篇
  2022年   37篇
  2021年   34篇
  2020年   35篇
  2019年   48篇
  2018年   64篇
  2016年   35篇
  2015年   47篇
  2014年   219篇
  2013年   148篇
  2012年   311篇
  2011年   321篇
  2010年   244篇
  2009年   200篇
  2008年   236篇
  2007年   282篇
  2006年   279篇
  2005年   241篇
  2004年   209篇
  2003年   229篇
  2002年   192篇
  2001年   144篇
  2000年   152篇
  1999年   88篇
  1998年   81篇
  1997年   83篇
  1996年   94篇
  1995年   94篇
  1994年   96篇
  1993年   57篇
  1992年   48篇
  1991年   59篇
  1990年   63篇
  1989年   73篇
  1988年   93篇
  1987年   89篇
  1986年   85篇
  1985年   97篇
  1984年   93篇
  1983年   93篇
  1982年   71篇
  1981年   67篇
  1980年   83篇
  1979年   37篇
  1977年   16篇
  1973年   15篇
  1964年   29篇
  1962年   23篇
  1959年   16篇
  1957年   15篇
排序方式: 共有5654条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
201.
In order to assess the effect of Social Security reform on current and future workers, it is essential to accurately characterize the initial situations of representative workers affected by reform. For the purpose of analyzing typical reforms, the most important characteristic of a worker is the level and pattern of his or her preretirement earnings. Under the current system, pensions are determined largely by the level of the workers' earnings averaged over their work life. However, several reform proposals would create individual retirement accounts for which the pension would depend on the investment accumulation within the account. Thus, the pension would also depend on the timing of the contributions into the account and hence on the exact shape of the worker's lifetime earnings profile. Most analysis of the distributional impact of reform has focused, however, on calculating benefit changes among a handful of hypothetical workers whose relative earnings are constant over their work life. The earnings levels are not necessarily chosen to represent the situations of workers who have typical or truly representative earnings patterns. Consequently, the results of such analysis can be misleading, especially if reform involves introducing a fundamentally new kind of pension formula. This article presents two broad approaches to creating representative earnings profiles for policy evaluation. First, we use standard econometric methods to predict future earnings for a representative sample of workers drawn from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP). Our statistical estimates are based on a simple representation of typical career earnings paths and a fixed-effect statistical specification. Because our estimation file contains information on each worker's annual earnings from 1951 through 1996 as reported in the Social Security Administration's earnings files, we have a record (though an incomplete one) of the actual earnings that will be used to determine future benefit payments. Our estimates of the earnings function permit us to make highly differentiated predictions of future earnings for each member of our sample. By combining the historical information on individual earnings with our prediction of future earnings up through the normal retirement age, our first approach produces tens of thousands of predicted career earnings paths that can be used in microsimulation policy analysis. Our second approach to creating lifetime earnings profiles is similar in some ways to the traditional method. For example, it is based on the creation of only a handful of "stylized" career earnings patterns. An important difference with the traditional method, however, is that we define the career earnings patterns so that they are truly representative of patterns observed in the workforce. We use simple mathematical formulas to characterize each stylized earnings pattern, and we then produce estimates of the average path of annual earnings for workers whose career earning path falls within each of the stylized patterns we have defined. Finally, we calculate the percentage of workers in successive birth-year cohorts who have earnings profiles that match each of the stylized earnings patterns. Although this method may seem simple, it allows the analyst to create stylized earnings patterns that are widely varied but still representative of earnings patterns observed among sizable groups of U.S. workers. The effects of policy reforms can then be calculated for workers with each of the stylized earnings patterns. Our analysis of U.S. lifetime earnings patterns and of the impact of selected policy reforms produces a number of findings about past trends in earnings, typical earnings patterns in the population, and the potential impact of reform. The analysis focuses on men and women born between 1931 and 1960. Along with earlier analysts, we find that men earn substantially higher lifetime wages than women and typically attain their peak career earnings at a somewhat earlier age. However, the difference in career earnings patterns between men and women has narrowed dramatically over time. Workers with greater educational attainment earn substantially higher wages than those with less education, and they attain their peak career earnings later in life. For example, among men with the least education, peak earnings are often attained around or even before age 40, whereas many men with substantial postsecondary schooling do not reach their peak career earnings until after 50. Our tabulations of the lifetime earnings profiles of the oldest cohorts (born around 1930) and projections of the earnings of the youngest profiles (born around 1960) imply that the inequality of lifetime earnings has increased noticeably over time. Women in the top one-fifth of female earners and men in the top one-fifth of male earners are predicted to receive a growing multiple of the economy-wide average wage during their career. Women born between 1931 and 1935 who were in the top fifth of female earners had lifetime average earnings that were approximately equal to the average economy-wide wage. In contrast, women born after 1951 who were in the top fifth of earners are predicted to earn almost 50 percent more, that is, roughly 150 percent of the economy-wide average wage. Women with a lower rank in the female earnings distribution will also see gains in their lifetime average earnings, but their gains are predicted to be proportionately much smaller than those of women with a high rank in the distribution. Men with high earnings are also predicted to enjoy substantial gains in their relative lifetime earnings, while men with a lower rank in the earnings distribution will probably see a significant erosion in their typical wages relative to the economy-wide average wage. That is mainly the result of a sharp decline in the relative earnings of low-wage men born after 1950. In creating stylized earnings profiles that are representative of those of significant minorities of U.S. workers, we emphasized three critical elements of the earnings path: the average level of earnings over a worker's career, the upward or downward trend in earnings from the worker's 30s through his or her early 60s, and the "sagging" or "hump-shaped" profile of earnings over the worker's career. That classification scheme yields 27 characteristic patterns of lifetime earnings. Surprisingly, the differnce between men and women within each of those categories is quite modest. The main difference between men and women is in the proportions of workers who fall in each category. Only 14 percent of men born between 1931 and 1940 fall in earnings categories with the lowest one-third of lifetime earnings, whereas 53 percent of women born in those years have low-average-earnings profiles. On the other hand, women born in those years are more likely to have a rising trend in lifetime earnings, while men are more likely to have a declining trend. We find that the distribution of lifetime earnings contains relatively more workers with below-average earnings and relatively fewer with very high earnings than assumed in the Social Security Administration's traditional policy analysis. For example, the "low earner" traditionally assumed by the Office of the Chief Actuary is assigned a level of average lifetime earnings that we find to be higher than the average earnings of persons in the bottom one-third of the lifetime earnings distribution. The stylized earnings profiles developed here can be used for policy evaluation, and the results can be compared with those from the more traditional analysis. That comparison produces several notable findings. Because earnings profiles that are actually representative of the population tend to have lower average earnings than assumed in the traditional analysis, workers typically accumulate somewhat less Social Security wealth than implied in the traditional analysis. On the other hand, because the basic benefit formula is tilted in favor of lower-income workers, the internal rate of return on Social Security contributions is somewhat higher than detected in the traditional analysis. Moreover, the primary insurance amount measured as a percentage of the worker's average indexed earnings tends to be higher than implied by the traditional analysis. Finally, the stylized earnings patterns can be used to compare benefit levels enjoyed by workers under the traditional Social Security formula and under an alternative plan based on individual investment accounts. That comparison shows, as expected, that the traditional formula favors low-wage workers and one-earner couples, while an investment account favors single, high-wage workers. Comparing two workers with the same lifetime average earnings, the traditional formula favors workers with rising earnings profiles (that is, with lifetime earnings heavily concentrated at the end of their career), while investment account pensions favor workers with declining earnings profiles (that is, with earnings concentrated early in their career).  相似文献   
202.
柬埔寨迄今发现的最早的高棉碑铭刻于公元611年,最早的梵文碑铭比它晚刻两年。从公元七世纪起,出现一些用两种文字刻成的可确定其年代的碑铭,给我们展示了柬埔寨社会构成的画面。这种画面与我们从中国资料看到的不同,因为这些碑铭表现的是宗教内容而不是世俗生活。根据碑铭,柬埔寨社会至少非正式地被划分为懂得梵文和仅仅懂得高棉语的两部分人。在好几百年的时间里,梵人被用于直接对神谈话的碑铭中,而高棉语则是柬埔寨  相似文献   
203.
以胡锦涛为总书记的新一届中央领导集体在执政党建设的理论创新方面有许多建树。突出地表现在在执政党的执政理念上,提出要“科学执政”、“民主执政”、“依法执政”;在执政党的保障机制上,提出要“加强党的先进性建设”;在执政党的价值取向上,提出要“以人为本”、“构建社会主义和谐社会”。  相似文献   
204.
汕头今年高考复读班火爆,不乏想上名校的高分生,专家提醒复读须慎重。 高考成绩达802分、已被某大学计算机专业录取的尖子生,却准备回校复读冲刺清华大学。日前,记者在采访汕头市部分高考复读  相似文献   
205.
206.
这篇文章总结了从1921年到1981年苏联青年研究的成就,引用了六十年中出版的近40部著作和调查材料。在总结和回顾苏联青年研究历史经验的基础上,作者主要分析了七十年代以来苏联青年的兴趣、爱好、需求和政治、职业趋向的发展变化,提出了急待研究和解决的问题。此外,作者还兼论了青年研究中的一些基本概念。所有这些对我国当前的青年研究和青年工作科学化都有一定的参考价值。  相似文献   
207.
俄罗斯具有丰富的自然资源和工艺潜力。为了民族的经济福利,需要保护资源,开发其潜力,谨慎地利用自然,人文和智能财富以及合理的经营开发制度。为此国际交换及外国投资问题就成为关键课题之一。 若不深入持久地参与国际劳动分工,不与商品、服务、资金、劳动力及科技信息等的国际动态紧密相联,没有一个国家能在现代世界上立足。为了适应采掘工业的投资服务需求,吸引外国资金已成为全世界的实践活动。现阶段在外国投资者或国际项目范围中,销售科技研究成果已成为常事。在现代化标准基础上要发展民族经济,如没有智能、劳动力的国际交换,不吸引外资,同时出口本国资金及工艺是行不通的,这是在全球范围内都适用的道理。  相似文献   
208.
有关货物所有权转移的法律规定是至关重要的,因为就所有权的转移而论、买卖合同的当事人通常不会表明他们的意图。加之,所有权一转移,风险也就转移,总而言之,只能提起与损害赔偿不同的价格诉讼。以下是有关的法律规定: 特定货物我们要考虑六种情况。 (1)第17条规定,凡特定或确定货物的买卖合同,就在双方愿意货物所有权转移之时,这些货物的所有权转移了。于是,为了确定双方的意愿起见,必须重视合同的条文,  相似文献   
209.
在深化国有企业改革,建立现代企业制度的过程中,必须全心全意依靠工人阶级。实践证明,国有企业改革没有广大工人群众的参与和支持,是不可能成功的。一、国有企业改革必须依靠工人阶级工人阶级既是国家的主人,也是企业的主人,承认这一点是坚持贯彻落实全心全意依靠工人阶级这个根本指导方针的前提,因为这事关改革能否坚持正确的方向和原则,事关我们党和国家的性质和前途命运。第一,我国宪法明确规定:“中华人民共和国是工人阶级领导的,以工农联盟为基础的人民民主专政的社会主义国家。”这使工人阶级和全体劳动人民作为国家主人的…  相似文献   
210.
发达国家的大多数人认为,“世界粮食问题”主要是指不发达国家还有很多人在忍饥挨饿.这个问题为什么会持续存在呢? 对世界各国的分析比较表明粮食充裕与人平收入之间有密切关系,在各个国家内部,对家庭消费的研究也表明存在这种密切的关系.这就说明,大多数饥民是贫穷国家的贫民.如此说来,世界粮食问题是贫穷导致的需求不足引起的. 但是,我们也可以从另一个角度来分析一些世界性的数据资料.在一些贫穷国家,没有足够的粮食满足公民的一般需要,许多国家粮食需求总量的增长快于供应总量的增长,过去  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号