首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   10770篇
  免费   353篇
各国政治   315篇
工人农民   520篇
世界政治   656篇
外交国际关系   337篇
法律   6828篇
中国共产党   34篇
中国政治   129篇
政治理论   2165篇
综合类   139篇
  2021年   62篇
  2020年   156篇
  2019年   139篇
  2018年   218篇
  2017年   252篇
  2016年   296篇
  2015年   241篇
  2014年   237篇
  2013年   912篇
  2012年   246篇
  2011年   303篇
  2010年   222篇
  2009年   293篇
  2008年   353篇
  2007年   370篇
  2006年   353篇
  2005年   329篇
  2004年   311篇
  2003年   261篇
  2002年   250篇
  2001年   363篇
  2000年   330篇
  1999年   271篇
  1998年   173篇
  1997年   125篇
  1996年   153篇
  1995年   122篇
  1994年   134篇
  1993年   132篇
  1992年   207篇
  1991年   259篇
  1990年   220篇
  1989年   209篇
  1988年   228篇
  1987年   215篇
  1986年   231篇
  1985年   200篇
  1984年   169篇
  1983年   166篇
  1982年   108篇
  1981年   133篇
  1980年   104篇
  1979年   108篇
  1978年   93篇
  1977年   87篇
  1976年   70篇
  1975年   72篇
  1974年   68篇
  1973年   79篇
  1969年   53篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 993 毫秒
251.
252.
Presidents traditionally have had great success when nominating justices to the Supreme Court, with confirmation being the norm and rejection being the rare exception. While the confirmation process usually ends with the nominee taking a seat on the Court, however, there is a great deal of variance in the amount of time it takes the Senate to act. To derive a theoretical explanation of this underlying dynamic in the confirmation process, we draw on a spatial model of presidential nominations to the Court. We then employ a hazard model to test this explanation, using data on all Supreme Court nominations and confirmations since the end of the Civil War. Our primary finding is that the duration of the confirmation process increases as the ideological distance between the president and the Senate increases. We also find evidence that suggests that the duration increases for critical nominees and chief justices and decreases for older nominees, current and previous senators, and nominees with prior experience on state and federal district courts .  相似文献   
253.
254.
Back to nature     
Howard L. Kaye 《Society》2003,40(2):48-52
  相似文献   
255.
256.
257.
258.
The alternative vote (AV) is a preferential electoral system that tends to reward political moderation and compromise. Fraenkel and Grofman have modeled the likely effects of AV in severely divided societies, in order to impugn AV as a tool of interethnic accommodation. In this response, I show that Fraenkel and Grofman’s model is based on extreme assumptions that bear no relation to party and voter behavior in such societies. Models based on realistic assumptions about strategic behavior and cross-national experience with AV both demonstrate that AV generally provides centripetal incentives that can contribute to interethnic coalition-building and accommodation.  相似文献   
259.
Islam  Muhammed N.  Winer  Stanley L. 《Public Choice》2004,118(3-4):289-323
Ronald Wintrobe (1990, 1998) has recently provided atheoretical foundation for estimating equations that attemptto explain the dependence of civil liberties and politicalrights in non-democratic regimes on the history of economicgrowth. This theory suggests that data from different kinds ofnon-democratic countries should not be pooled without allowingcoefficients to vary with regime type. It also placesinteresting restrictions on the signs of the coefficients ofeconomic growth in equations explaining freedom in the typesof regimes Wintrobe identifies. In this paper, we employ theserestrictions to test Wintrobe's theory. Some additionalhypotheses about the difference between democratic andnon-democratic regimes and about the role of education, notconsidered by Wintrobe, are also investigated.The results indicate clearly that the relationship between thedegree of freedom – as measured by the sum of the Gastilindexes of civil liberties and political rights – andeconomic growth varies significantly across all types ofregimes. Totalitarians (that attempt to maximize power) areclearly different than tinpots (that just attempt to maintainpower) in this respect, and non-democratic regimes differ fromdemocracies. Other aspects of the theory are partiallyconfirmed. In particular, in totalitarian regimes, positivegrowth reduces freedom, and negative growth increases it insome specifications. The theory predicts the opposite patternfor tinpots, and we do find that negative growth reducesfreedom in tinpot regimes. However, positive growth in tinpotsalso appears to reduce freedom in some cases, which is not inaccord with the theory. Secondary schooling has a positive effect on freedom, as inprevious empirical work, a result that is shown here to holdeven when each type of regime is considered separately. Butthe effect of primary schooling is different: in tinpot andtotalitarian regimes, but not in democracies, primaryschooling is associated with reduced freedom.  相似文献   
260.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号