全文获取类型
收费全文 | 8474篇 |
免费 | 6篇 |
专业分类
各国政治 | 225篇 |
工人农民 | 1074篇 |
世界政治 | 215篇 |
外交国际关系 | 296篇 |
法律 | 4762篇 |
中国政治 | 5篇 |
政治理论 | 1892篇 |
综合类 | 11篇 |
出版年
2022年 | 3篇 |
2021年 | 6篇 |
2020年 | 11篇 |
2019年 | 6篇 |
2018年 | 1279篇 |
2017年 | 1205篇 |
2016年 | 1017篇 |
2015年 | 64篇 |
2014年 | 27篇 |
2013年 | 53篇 |
2012年 | 187篇 |
2011年 | 918篇 |
2010年 | 1015篇 |
2009年 | 585篇 |
2008年 | 738篇 |
2007年 | 700篇 |
2006年 | 17篇 |
2005年 | 67篇 |
2004年 | 170篇 |
2003年 | 142篇 |
2002年 | 30篇 |
2001年 | 3篇 |
2000年 | 9篇 |
1999年 | 3篇 |
1998年 | 14篇 |
1997年 | 14篇 |
1996年 | 28篇 |
1995年 | 35篇 |
1994年 | 27篇 |
1993年 | 4篇 |
1992年 | 6篇 |
1990年 | 7篇 |
1989年 | 3篇 |
1988年 | 2篇 |
1987年 | 3篇 |
1986年 | 3篇 |
1985年 | 3篇 |
1984年 | 10篇 |
1983年 | 12篇 |
1982年 | 7篇 |
1980年 | 3篇 |
1979年 | 6篇 |
1978年 | 12篇 |
1977年 | 11篇 |
1976年 | 4篇 |
1975年 | 2篇 |
1970年 | 1篇 |
1969年 | 1篇 |
1968年 | 1篇 |
1965年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有8480条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
831.
Using a neoclassical growth model augmented with human capital, we investigate the impact of the presence of state owned enterprises (SOEs) on macroeconomic performance in China, using provincial data from 1990 to 2004. We estimate a macroeconomic model with panel methods to explain changes in labor productivity resulting from standard influences as well as presence of the SOE sector measured in five different ways. While controlling for growth in the labor force and physical capital, government size, exposure to trade and change in economic structure, we conclude that the relative share of the SOE sector has no significant influence on macroeconomic performance in China during our sample period. 相似文献
832.
Gordon Tullock 《Public Choice》2009,138(1-2):3-8
Many mechanisms (such as auctions) efficiently allocate an asset to the firm which values it most highly. But sometimes the asset’s owner may benefit from the transfer only if the asset is not too valuable to potential buyers. In this setting, we examine the efficiency of mechanisms when the potential buyers have private information about the asset’s value. We show that rent seeking, and lobbying, rather than merely wasting resources, can lead to allocations which are close to efficient. 相似文献
833.
834.
835.
Bryan-Paul Frost 《Society》2009,46(1):90-92
836.
837.
Vincent Lemieux Genecive Ledoux 《Canadian public administration. Administration publique du Canada》1983,26(3):402-419
Sommaire: Nos sociétés modernes font l'objet de débats très controversés autour du problème de I'accès à l'information gouvernementale. Une approche systémique permet entre aittres de prendre conscience des différents enjeux inhérents au contrôle de cette information. Elle expliqrie pourquoi certains Etats sont plus en-clins que d'autres à favoriser 1'accès à l'information gouvernementale. Dans cette approche, la société est perçue comme un système d'acteurs dont les trois principaux sont le gouvernement, les intermediaires et les différents publics, avec en plus les acteurs externes dans I'environnement. Ces acteurs sont soumis à des règles normatives ou pragniatiques. Leur pouvoir respectif de contrôle est loin d'être équivalent. Le pouvoir du gouvrnement sur les différentes dimensions de la communication le démarque fortement de ses compétiteurs. Certaines propriétés générales dri système, de caractère- plus macroscopique, sont ensuite dégagées, soit la tendance gÆné rale à l'amplification de I'information gouvernementale ainsi que la tendance a l'amplification des prohlémes contradictoires reliés au trop grand secret de l'information gouvernementale d'une part, et à la trop petite protection de l'information personnelle d'autre part. Le gouvernement québécois a maintenant legiféré dans ce domaine. mais la loi d'accès ne inodifie pas fondanientalement les propriétés generales du systeme ni le pouvoir prédominant du gouvernement sur les autres acteurs politiques. Abstract: In modern societies, the problem of access to government information has been the subject of passionate debates. The systemic approach offers, among other things, an awareness of the various stakes inherent in the control of this information. It explains why some countries are more favourably disposed toward easy access to government information. In this approach, society is perceived as a players' system, the three main actors being the government, the intermediaries and the public, with, in addition, outside actors. The actors are subjected to normative or pragmatic rules but their respective control is far from being of equal value. Through its power on the various dimensions of communications, the government is very much set apart from its competitors. Some general and more macroscopic characteristics of the system are then oAPred: on the one hand, the general tendency to exaggerate government information as well as the tendency to overstate the contradictory problems. 相似文献
838.
Fukunari Kimura 《Asia Europe Journal》2003,1(2):197-211
East Asia, including Northeast Asia and Southeast Asia, has developed tightly-linked production/distribution networks through
globalizing corporate activities. The vertical chain of production in East Asia has been even more sophisticated than economic
integration in East Europe or Latin America. However, the political environment of East Asia for trade and investment has
been far from borderless. The integration effort at the policy level has been very much limited so far, due to the historical
background as well as geopolitics surrounding East Asia.
The Asian currency/financial crisis provided these countries a historical turning point. After the burst of the crisis, East
Asians realized that they have to take care of themselves in their difficulties, not depending on outside forces. A natural
choice for them was to step into the realm of regionalism. In 1998, Japan and Korea officially announced that they would discard
the long-lasting GATT/WTO-only approach and adapt the multi-layered approach, including both regionalism and multilateralism.
The ultimate goal of regionalism would be a region-wide integration including ASEAN+3. As a steppingstone, Japan signed the
Japan-Singapore Economic Partnership Agreement (JSEPA) in January 2002. In a parallel move, the ASEAN and China Leaders announced
in November 2001 the establishment of an ASEAN-China Free Trade Area (ACFTA) within 10 years.
This article will follow up the most recent advancement of regional institutional building in East Asia with the emphasis
on peculiar characteristics of economic integration in the region and discuss its implications for Asia-Europe relations.
This paper is heavily drawn from Kimura (2002, 2003). 相似文献
839.
Robert Ash 《Asia Europe Journal》2003,1(2):281-289
China's continental physical expanse has been a dominant, shaping influence of its political, social and economic development
throughout its modern history. Thanks to its relative ethnic homogeneity, as well as the absence of political reform, it has
– unlike the former Soviet Union – preserved its unity as a state. Nevertheless, regionalism remains a powerful counterpoint
to centralisation in China. In particular, under the impact of post-1978 economic reforms, differentials and tensions between
provinces and regions have emerged as a potent force, threatening the authority and power of Beijing.
This article begins by seeking to explore some of the regional forms in which economic change has manifested itself during
the last two decades. It highlights the unique problems faced by an economy that is still in transition in a country as large
as China. Brief consideration is also given to the wider regional context in which China is sometimes placed as the central
player – namely, that of `Greater China'.
At the heart of the article is a case study that examines the evolution of a particular kind of regionalism, captured in the
economic integration – even symbiosis - between Hong Kong and Guangdong. The question is addressed whether the form of regionalism
contained within the forging of an ever-closer economic relationship between these two areas of South China can be a model
for the integration of other regions both within and across China's national boundaries.
Hong Kong's transformation from a tiny, dependent, colonial enclave into one of the most successful economies in the world
is one of the most remarkable stories of post-World War II economic history. During the 1960s and 1970s, Hong Kong's growth
record was unmatched anywhere else in the world. But by the beginning of the 1980s, high land rents and spiralling wages started
to erode the international competitiveness that had been the basis of Hong Kong's previous economic success. By a happy coincidence,
however, the emergence of such pressures coincided with the opening of China to the outside world. China's `open door' policy
thereby made available to Hong Kong entrepreneurs a huge, hitherto untapped reservoir of cheap labour and gave them access
to inexpensive factory sites just across the border in Guangdong. It was a lifeline to which they responded eagerly and, through
the relocation of their factories, provided the means whereby Hong Kong manufacturers discovered a new lease of life.
The benefits associated with this process accrued not only to Hong Kong through the regeneration of its manufacturing industry.
Rather, it was a two-way process that also facilitated economic growth, structural transformation and improvements in living
standards in Guangdong (above all, in the Pearl River Delta). In short, the process became the basis of deepening integration
between the economies of the two regions. Indeed, it was the key element in the emergence of a new regional economic grouping,
known as `Greater China' – an informal triangular partnership between Hong Kong, Taiwan and two southern Chinese provinces
(Guangdong and Fujian).
The emergence of `Greater China' can be regarded as a particular manifestation of the coastal bias that has so strongly characterised
China's economic trajectory under reform. To this day, the triangular economic nexus between Hong Kong, Taiwan and South China
remains an important dimension of China's external economic relations, even if developments in other coastal provinces have
caused it to weaken. To what extent recent and future developments have challenged and will continue to challenge the regionalism
inherent in the original notion of Greater China is something that deserves close attention. Not least, the strategic initiative
of opening up China's western regions poses interesting and important questions that touch on future developments of `trans-nationalism'
and `trans-regionalism' affecting China. 相似文献
840.
This paper places the contemporary study of regionalism in historical context. It argues that the study of regionalism has
occurred in two waves. The first gathered pace as a sub-field of International Relations from the late 1950s and the second
emerged in the context of the globalisation of the late 1980s and the 1990s.
RID="*"
ID="*" This paper, originally presented as a lecture to the Asia Europe Foundation University, 7th Summer School, Barcelona: November 11, 2002, represents an abbreviated and revised version of Shaun Breslin and Richard Higgott
(2000) Studying Regions: Learning from the Old Constructing the New, New Political Economy 5 (3): 333–352. Permission of the Editors of New Political Economy to publish in this form is gratefully acknowledged. The support of the Economic and Social Research Council in the writing
of this paper is also gratefully acknowledged. 相似文献