首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   19161篇
  免费   517篇
各国政治   845篇
工人农民   711篇
世界政治   1603篇
外交国际关系   724篇
法律   11073篇
中国共产党   2篇
中国政治   90篇
政治理论   4437篇
综合类   193篇
  2020年   235篇
  2019年   281篇
  2018年   370篇
  2017年   444篇
  2016年   474篇
  2015年   326篇
  2014年   374篇
  2013年   2002篇
  2012年   435篇
  2011年   471篇
  2010年   387篇
  2009年   429篇
  2008年   496篇
  2007年   505篇
  2006年   497篇
  2005年   448篇
  2004年   470篇
  2003年   472篇
  2002年   438篇
  2001年   723篇
  2000年   649篇
  1999年   540篇
  1998年   332篇
  1997年   275篇
  1996年   231篇
  1995年   248篇
  1994年   278篇
  1993年   255篇
  1992年   364篇
  1991年   398篇
  1990年   358篇
  1989年   381篇
  1988年   353篇
  1987年   366篇
  1986年   371篇
  1985年   361篇
  1984年   318篇
  1983年   346篇
  1982年   284篇
  1981年   257篇
  1980年   196篇
  1979年   256篇
  1978年   187篇
  1977年   165篇
  1976年   148篇
  1975年   133篇
  1974年   158篇
  1973年   133篇
  1972年   120篇
  1971年   100篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
981.
982.
Clark  Derek J. 《Public Choice》1997,93(1-2):119-130
This paper considers a form of the Tullock imperfectly discriminating rent-seeking game in which the contestants are uncertain about the value of a bias parameter in the probability of winning function. Beliefs about this unknown parameter are not constrained to be static; we consider two methods by which the players' prior beliefs on this parameter can be updated. First, we allow for information to emerge by considering the case in which the game is played twice, with the outcome of the first game known before the second begins. The identity of the winner of the first contest represents information which emerges endogenously that can be used to revise beliefs on the unknown bias parameter. Second, information can be produced outside of the model by an external agency; this gives rise to exogenous learning. We consider the consequences for rent-seeking in each of these two cases.  相似文献   
983.
Clark  Derek J. 《Public Choice》1997,93(1-2):179-195
This paper considers the division of a public budget among competing interests. The planner determines the optimal allocation by maximizing a weighted social welfare function. These weights reflect society's attitudes to different recipient groups, and are not constrained to be constant. By exerting “pressure”, the recipients can attempt to manipulate the weights and hence influence the division of the budget. The amount of resources used on pressure, and the effects on the preference weights are calculated. An important parameter in the model is the elasticity of pressure, for which an appropriate estimate is presented from the case of competition for a share of a health services budget in Norway.  相似文献   
984.
Alexander  Barbara J. 《Public Choice》1997,91(3-4):251-269
Models of prototyped and non-prototyped competitions for prime contracts from the U.S. defense department suggest that the latter are much more vulnerable to bid-rigging than are the former. Subcontracting data reveal that pairs of firms who have been rivals in major non-prototyped competitions have a larger number of subcontracts with one another than do other pairs of firms. The analysis concludes that subcontracts may serve as vehicles for division of the spoils of collusive bidding on prime contracts.  相似文献   
985.
986.
987.
Abstract In several recent studies George Rabinowitz and his co–authors challenge the 'classical' spatial model of issue voting, the proximity model, by introducing a directional model. In this article we examine whether different measurement of perceived issue positions of candidates or parties leads to diverging judgments about the predictive power of the directional model (which is claimed to be empirically superior), as compared to the proximity model, using data from the USA and Germany. The results demonstrate that the measurement preferred by Rabinowitz et al. tends to bias empirical findings in favour of directional theory. If we use a more plausible operational definition of issue positions of candidates and parties the directional model in both countries fails to turn out superior.  相似文献   
988.
Colin J. Bennett 《管理》1997,10(3):213-233
This article examines different explanations for the cross–national diffusion of three recent innovations in bureaucratic accountability—the institution of the ombudsman, freedom of information legislation and data protection (information privacy) law. The first two explanations are based on the assumption that these innovations are by–products of modernization, either the growth of the state or democratization. The third assumes that policy is shaped through processes of international communication. A combination of methodologies is employed to conclude that while the growth of government and liberal democratic values are necessary conditions for the adoption of all three policy instruments, they are not sufficient conditions. The pattern of adoption observed is best explained by examining how evidence about these respective policies flows from adopting states to non–adopters. In the case of the ombudsman, this process can be characterized as one of lesson–drawing; for freedom of information, evidence is used for legitimation purposes; for data protection, the diffusion is attributable to harmonization through international organizations. Policy transfer is hence a multi–faceted concept that embraces a number of distinct processes of transnational learning and communication.  相似文献   
989.
990.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号