首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   851篇
  免费   61篇
各国政治   15篇
工人农民   39篇
世界政治   19篇
外交国际关系   21篇
法律   260篇
中国共产党   46篇
中国政治   139篇
政治理论   94篇
综合类   279篇
  2023年   8篇
  2022年   6篇
  2021年   15篇
  2020年   23篇
  2019年   23篇
  2018年   15篇
  2017年   25篇
  2016年   30篇
  2015年   23篇
  2014年   41篇
  2013年   76篇
  2012年   55篇
  2011年   56篇
  2010年   40篇
  2009年   55篇
  2008年   48篇
  2007年   65篇
  2006年   63篇
  2005年   54篇
  2004年   49篇
  2003年   52篇
  2002年   38篇
  2001年   27篇
  2000年   16篇
  1999年   3篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   1篇
  1996年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
排序方式: 共有912条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
911.
The likelihood that longevity will continue to increase has generated a search for regulation that make people work longer as they live longer, and thus not just containing pension expenditure but also enlarging labor supply, economic growth, and tax revenue. In public pension policy, Nordic countries have led the world with three types of approaches aimed at making people retire later. The first came when Sweden, followed by Finland and Norway, installed life expectancy coefficients in benefit calculation formulas. The second followed as Finland introduced age-related accrual rates and the third when Denmark indexed the pensionable age to developments in life expectancy. Since economic incentive-based regulations failed to raise exit ages sufficiently, Finland and Sweden subsequently linked pensionable ages to life expectancy like Denmark. While this policy brings out inequalities in health and workability, the fact that countries found it necessary to index the pensionable age to longevity instead of just relying on economic incentives in regulating retirement behavior may hold lessons for other countries.  相似文献   
912.
The U.S. Occupational Safety and Health Administration establishes incentives for safety by setting and enforcing regulatory standards. Using four and a half decades of inspection data, this article provides a comprehensive analysis of the factors underpinning penalties following fatalities. The “fatality premium” for regulatory violations following a worker death is quite modest and is several orders of magnitude below the value-of-a-statistical-life figure needed to establish efficient levels of deterrence in the absence of all other financial incentives. Although there are low statutory caps on penalties, only 8% of the penalties for violations involving fatalities are constrained by the cap, suggesting that current statutes establish norms for reasonable penalty amounts. In situations involving a fatality at firms with union representation during the inspection, the enforcement sanctions are more stringent. Fatalities involving migrant laborers are less heavily penalized.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号