首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   84篇
  免费   3篇
各国政治   9篇
世界政治   9篇
外交国际关系   5篇
法律   38篇
政治理论   26篇
  2023年   1篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   2篇
  2020年   1篇
  2019年   3篇
  2018年   6篇
  2017年   6篇
  2016年   5篇
  2015年   1篇
  2014年   1篇
  2013年   14篇
  2012年   4篇
  2011年   1篇
  2010年   3篇
  2009年   2篇
  2008年   6篇
  2007年   3篇
  2006年   3篇
  2005年   3篇
  2004年   2篇
  2003年   1篇
  2002年   3篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   1篇
  1999年   1篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   1篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   2篇
  1994年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1980年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
  1971年   1篇
排序方式: 共有87条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
In the presented oversight model, in which a regulatory agency may collude with regulatees, a watchdog organization may scrutinize the agency’s decision-making and find evidence speaking for collusive behavior. Found evidence is of a specific, stochastic quality. Courts will overturn the administrative decision when the evidence presented in court exceeds a minimum quality standard set by the political principal. Lowering the quality standard increases the odds of finding evidence of sufficient quality and, hence, leads to increasing collusion deterrence and to a lower probability of acquitting collusive administrators (type I error), but also to a higher probability of convicting an innocent administrator (type II error). It is shown that, when welfare-maximization gives rise to an interior solution, the welfare-maximizing standard of evidence is lower than the one that merely minimizes the costs of legal errors without taking deterrence costs into account, but will imply incomplete deterrence. However, conditions can and will be identified under which both error cost minimization and complete deterrence coincide with welfare-maximization.  相似文献   
2.
3.
Hartmut Kliemt 《Public Choice》2005,125(1-2):203-213
The paper explores some of the surprisingly many relations between theories of public choice and political philosophy. Focusing on variants of Homo oeconomicus it does so systematically rather than historically. But it factors in the history of the two disciplines along with some recent developments in (experimental) economics. This sheds new light on the counterfactual assumption that in politics everybody should be supposed to be a knave and suggests that we better seek factually sound behavioral foundations for Public Choice.  相似文献   
4.
This article explores ‘peace days’ in English schools as a form of peace education. From a historical overview of academic discussions on peace education in the US and Great Britain since the First World War, we identify three key factors important for peace education: the political context, the place in which peace days occur and pedagogical imperatives of providing a certain narrative of the sources of violence in politics. Although contemporary militarism and neoliberalism reduce the terrains for peace studies in English schools, peace days allow teachers to carve out spaces for peace education. Peace days in Benfield School, Newcastle and Comberton Village College, Cambridgeshire, are considered as case studies. We conclude with reflections on the opportunities and limitations of this approach to peace education, and on how peace educators and activists could enlarge its reach.  相似文献   
5.
Hartmut Kliemt 《Public Choice》1994,79(3-4):341-353
It is shown that the basic normative argument of thecalculus is moored to a collectivistic unanimity norm. As most scholars working in the field of public choice, including the authors of the seminalcalculus, would otherwise reject collectivistic normative premises, a re-interpretation of the status of the unanimity principle of thecalculus seems unavoidable. The paper argues that this can be done if the basic formation of a society is not characterized as starting from a given set of individuals but rather in terms of the formation of clubs. This amounts to the same thing as substituting universalistic ethical premises by particularistic ones which are more in line with standard economic methodology.  相似文献   
6.
René Dumont, Cuba est‐il Socialiste?, Paris, Seuil, 1970. 246 pp., Sw. Fr. 6.50. Richard R. Fagen, The Transformation of Political Culture in Cuba, Stanford U.P., 1969. ix+271 pp., $8.50 (£4). Michel Gutelman, L'Agriculture Socialisée à Cuba, Paris, Maspéro, 1967, 229 pp., Fr. 18.80. K. S. Karol, Les Guerrilléros au Pouvoir: l'itinéraire politique de la révolution cubaine, Paris, Robert Laffont, 1970. 606 pp., Sw. Fr. 31.30 (to be published in English by Hill and Wang, New York, as Guerillas in Power: the Course of the Cuban Revolution). James O'Connor, The Origins of Socialism in Cuba, Ithaca and London, Cornell U.P., 1970. viii+338 pp., $10 (£4.75).  相似文献   
7.
8.
9.
10.
The paper uses annual data from a panel of 334 Polish industrial enterprises over the period 1983–1988 to test empirically a simple neoclassical approach to the socialist labor market. First, an enterprise production function is estimated. The paper finds that for most enterprises, the resulting estimated marginal product of labor exceeds the wage paid by the enterprise by a considerable margin, suggesting general excess demand for labor. The paper then looks at how the difference between the MPL and the wage is related to the rate of change of employment, and finds that firms where the MPL is higher than the wage — firms which in a neoclassical model would have a large excess demand for labor — do not shed labor any more slowly than other firms.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号